From NPR:
"There's no credit. How can you do business without credit?" he asks.
Greek banks have little money to lend out, while foreign lenders, which once flooded Greek businesses with loan offers, no longer want to do business in the country. The possibility that Greece might leave the eurozone, however slim, makes lending money there too risky.
It's a huge challenge for companies like Kir-Yianni, which have to import virtually all of the materials and equipment they use in their production. Kir-Yianni buys bottles from Italy, paper from Turkey, barrels from France and cork from Portugal.
What the NPR broadcast is describing, though it does not go into the economic details, is a phenomenon called Wicksellian Rot. Entrepreneurs in Greece are suffering from not having the money at hand to make their exchanges. This does not necessitate that what they are doing is economically unprofitable, indeed in the case of many it seems that they are plenty profitable, but that they suffer a want of physical money to complete their exchanges with other people. They know that they can make mutually beneficial trades with other people and they have done so in the past, but this exchange cannot be completed because of a lack of money. Thus parts of the Greek economy, which could otherwise be prosperous, are in a state of economic malaise due to a simple lack of cash.
The Euro is leaving Greece. As can be gathered from the broadcast, and which is corroborated by other reports, there is not enough Euros in Greece to fulfill the demand for money and so patterns of trade are grinding to a halt. This in turn is exacerbating the Greek economy as those few productive sectors in the economy are brought down as the Wicksellian rot brings down the economy. The natural process of this crisis is that capital will flee Greece into other parts of the world, and especially of the Euro-zone, until the overall price-level in Greece. This can be crudely shown with a basic supply-and-demand diagram, with the price-level on the ordinate and the quantity of money on the abscissa:
The right-ward sloping blue curve is the demand for money. It slopes that way because as the price level increases, each unit of cash will chase less goods hence to maintain their power to buy goods, in econ-speak their purchasing-power, people will demand more money. The purple line is the supply of money. It is vertical there because we shall assume here that the supply of money is endogenous, the product of the decisions of central-bankers and savers for reason outside of the model. Here, the initial price-level shown by the red dashed line no longer brings the demand and supply of money into equilibrium. Instead, the demand for money at that price-level exceeds the supply resulting in a large shortage of money whose effects we now see in Greece. The two can be brought back into equilibrium if the general price level in Greece decline by a process of systemic deflation; however, this is a process that has proved to be devastating for prosperity as shown by the British deflation of the 1920s after the Bank of England returned to the gold standard's pre-war parity even after half a decade of inflationary politices.
This can be avoided and there is a way to bring back monetary equilibrium without the price-level adjusting. This is possible if the Greek government were to expand the money supply as to bring it into equilibrium at the current price-level. This can be graphically represented as so:
Even though this would disturb the economy in its own ways, expanding the money supply would enable Greek entrepreneurs who have viable businesses to get the cash they need. In addition, since the Greek unit of money would have to decrease in value with respect to foreign monies, Greek goods would be less expensive than goods from other nations leading to a comparative advantage for Greek exports.
None of this is to happen soon, though. The Greek government has no control over their money and the nation is stuck in a union to the benefit of fiscally sound countries. Due to the loyalty of the EU to the idea of a united Europe and because the Euro is seen as an essential tenet of a united Europe, the Greek economy is simply left to go about the long process of deflation (while at the same time having to abide by austerity measures enforced by the EU). If Greece were to simply leave the Euro and adopt the Drachma, then Wicksellian rot could be avoided by expanding the money supply and the Greeks could use devaluation as a tool for getting out of the crisis.
In the short term, this is not to be for Eurocrats can continue to delude themselves that Greece can somehow remain in the Eurozone without loosing a decade of economic growth. In the long term, though, the Euro will leave Greece and the conditions of Wicksellian rot will worsen until finally the Greek government expands the money supply. What they use to initially expand the money supply may not be called Drachmas at first. They may very well be promises to pay Euros to the holders of the notes. However, they will be Drachmas in all but name and it is very likely that Greece will only formally sever its ties to the Euro after the informal ties had already cut themselves. This is all speculation, but what we can be certain of is that as long as Greece is in the Euro, there is no hope for the Greek economy. Until political hopes give way to economic reality, Wicksellian rot will worsen in Greece.
QE3: A Look at the Micro-Foundations
To start off, any judgment of the new round of Quantitative Easing must make clear its own opinion on the problem that the Federal Open Market Committee hopes to alleviate with it: persistent unemployment that has been the norm over the past four years.
The problems the American economy is suffering from are neither supply-side nor demand-side problems. To even draw the two curves would to abstract away from most of the problems that we have suffered and are suffering from. The fundamental problem is an economy that has substituted debt for productivity in the past and that made serious malinvestments in the housing and financial sectors. To put it in terms of Arnold Kling’s language of Patterns of Sustainable Specialization and Trade: over the past decade (at least) the new patterns of specialization and trade (e.g. construction and financial jocks) that have driven the growth in spending in the American economy were driven by borrowing. Those patterns could only last as long as the credit was loose and the markets did not realize the house of cards they were built on.
Now that that house has collapsed, it is of no surprise that the patterns of specialization and trade it produced have been disrupted. A result of this has been that spending in the American economy has also plummeted along with those patterns. In addition, median households can no longer use cheap credit in order to expand their consumption beyond their disposable income, so this has also contributed to the fall in spending. These micro-foundations to the fall in spending in the American economy make me skeptical that NGDP could have even stayed on its historical average baseline in 2008. It seems to me like spending had to fall with the declining PSST and along with that NGDP. Any attempt to pump spending back into those sectors would have been patching the problem rather than addressing the serious long-term sustainability issues they had. A nation simply cannot grow by credit forever.
Since the problems were debt and malinvestments, the only two solutions that would truly bring back economic health are deleveraging and economic recalculation (the reinvestment of malinvested assets to more productive uses). This is a process that no central banker can solve. Contra Keynes and Krugman, the problem of recession is not a problem about the insufficient use of technical knowledge on part of decision-makers in the government. Instead, it is a evolutionary process by which one of the most complex systems in the entire universe adapts to new conditions by the actions of millions of dispersed human beings, all with their own knowledge and vision of the world, guided by the mechanisms of the market. To interfere with that is to risk the entire process never truly adapting to those new conditions. As Joseph Schumpeter said in his article :Depressions: Can We Learn From Past Experiences?”:
(O)ur analysis leads us to believe that recovery is sound only if it does come of itself. For any revival which is due merely to artificial stimulus leaves part of the work of depressions undeone and adds, to the undigested remnant of the maladjutment, new maladjustments of its own which have to be liquidated in turn, thus threatening business with another crisis ahead.
The question of the day: what should this lead us to think about QE3?
For one thing, it should make us very suspicious of the FOMC’s decision to buy Mortgage-Backed Securities. Most of them are junk and should be treated as junk by policy-makers if policy is going to be neutral with respect to the process of recalculation in the housing sector. The Federal Reserve buying them does not correspond to that criterion of neutrality. Capital Economics has estimated that the Federal Reserve will have to buy $1 trillion in Mortgage-Backed Securities over the next three years to push unemployment down to 7 percent. This will have benefit those who have held onto those assets, a nefarious process that will reward failure rather than raising those up who made the best decisions over the years to the top. This contributes to the fragility of the markets and prevents the evolution of robust institutions that can endure through sudden changes in the economic data.
Then again, if the Federal Reserve were to buy $1 trillion in bonds from the US Treasury, that would also create perverse incentives in government budgeting. Perhaps there is no asset that Fed could buy while obeying the neutrality criterion, but to buy assets that are so connected with the 2008 Financial Crisis and the problems that caused it is an utter violation.
The greatest error of QE3, its designers and its advocates is that they are simply looking at spending. What they want is for monetary spending to simply stimulate spending in the economy to boost aggregate demand. However, there is no such thing as aggregate demand. There is only a variety of heterogeneous demands for many heterogeneous products, none of which are fungible. Aggregate demand is just a fiction of bad macroeconomics. By focusing on spending alone and not the channels of trade that spending flows through à la PSST, that perspective misses the entire process by which an economy crashes and that proceeds to recover.
Once we take our eyes off of the golden calf of aggregate demand and stop thinking purely in terms of fungible “spending”, we can truly focus at the problems at hand: the PSST within the economy and the institutions that facilitate them. This is no my last word on the subject and for lack of time (as well as trying not to take on too much for a single post) I'm unable to consider concerns about debt-deflation found in Irving Fisher's great paper: “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions.” Of course, that is no mere lacuna so treat this all as merely a process of getting the true, yet forthcoming, understanding.
Posted by Harrison Searles on 09/15/2012 at 09:30 PM in Commentary, Current Affairs, Monetary Policy | Permalink | Comments (0)
Reblog (0) | | |